Âé¶¹ÒùÔº


How the philosophy of the past can help us imagine the economy of the future

How the philosophy of the past can help us imagine the economy of the future
Credit: Monstera Production from Pexels

The economy keeps making headlines for all the wrong reasons—stories about , and a looming have been frequently making the front page these days.

The widening the gap between the rich and poor—a problem that was already accelerated by the and the .

The richest country in the world, , is among the most drastic examples of this trend. . A typical worker, on the other hand, only goes home with 12 percent more money than workers from 1978 did.

As a demonstrates, rising CEO pay does not reflect a change in the value of skills—it represents a shift in power. Over decades, American politics has undermined the bargaining power of workers by and self-organizing efforts, such as .

The growing wealth of a minority at the expense of the majority means power is concentrated in the hands of a few people, . It's not surprising that figures such as , and have a disproportional impact on our communities—sometimes with devastating consequences that threaten our .

Economics with a human face

It's more necessary than ever before to re-examine the fundamentals of our economic order. The search for alternative economic models, however, is made difficult by conventional thinking patterns.

Many believe between a capitalist market economy on the one hand and a socialist-planned economy on the other.

Although we live in a world that defines in absolutist terms, it doesn't have to be this way. We argue that the psychological and social perspectives on economy that were developed by 19th-century philosophers such as , and can help us re-imagine economics with a .

These thinkers were convinced that a good economic order had to incorporate elements of classic capitalism (such as a in goods and services) with elements of classic socialism (such as of the ). This is what we call .

Hegel and the problem of affluence

Hegel is a good example of an economic pluralist thinker. In his , he presented an . He discussed the market and its operating principles, social inequality and even the formation of desires through advertisements and consumer culture.

Among the many topics he examined was the . Hegel was not just worried about the poverty created by the modern market economy, but also about the concentration of extreme wealth in few hands.

Writing hundreds of years before modern multi-billionaires arrived on the scene, "both of these sides, poverty and affluence, represent the scourge (Verderben) of Civil Society."

Hegel's analysis is even more prescient: He believed affluence created the counter-intuitive tendency among the affluent to feel victimized and disenfranchized by society. As a result, the affluent perceived all social demands, like taxes, as unjustified incursions into their personal freedom.

Hegel thought this sense of victimization could lead to an unexpected bond between those at the very top of the economic pyramid and those at the bottom—a bond that overcame differences in lifestyle and mutual antipathy to form an alliance that attacks from both sides. The phenomenon of is an interesting modern example of this.

Re-imagining the economy

Unlike some later socialists, Hegel did not think problems of affluence were best rectified by introducing a planned economy that enforces wealth equality. Instead, his approach was pluralistic.

He made a case for a exchange paired with co-operative modes of production, which are—in some respects—similar to .

If most economic production in society was organized co-operatively, Hegel believed, wealthier subjects would be embedded in economic decision-making with others, replacing the detrimental "bond of victimization" between the rich and poor with a collective identity based on shared economic agency.

When reimagining our current economic order, we can take a page out of Hegel's handbook by focusing on : economic ventures that are that make productive decisions together, often—albeit not always—in a democratic manner.

Under what conditions are such co-operative modes of production successful? How can the state incentivize these forms of production within the existing market ? And are these worker co-operatives really a way to achieve economic justice? These are the questions that, inspired by the past, might help us imagine a new, pluralist, more equal and human-centric economic future.

Provided by The Conversation

This article is republished from under a Creative Commons license. Read the .The Conversation

Citation: How the philosophy of the past can help us imagine the economy of the future (2023, January 5) retrieved 31 August 2025 from /news/2023-01-philosophy-economy-future.html
This document is subject to copyright. Apart from any fair dealing for the purpose of private study or research, no part may be reproduced without the written permission. The content is provided for information purposes only.

Explore further

Governments must 'change the way the economy works' after COVID-19, says new report

3 shares

Feedback to editors